I was trying to suspend judgment as I read Yale professor Stephen L. Carter's call for "shared sacrifice" from all Americans, because he was trying to sound all reasonable and non-partisan. Then I hit the following paragraph, and I was certain he was either ignorant or a fraud:
But progressivity is merely one factor in working out tax rates. It isn't the reason taxes exist. They exist to raise revenue, a point easily forgotten in the rhetoric of the day. And there isn't nearly enough income in the upper bracket to make a serious dent in the nation's debt.
First part -- true. Second part -- dead wrong. And he either knew it, so he didn't even attempt to back up this bald assertion, or else he was too lazy to look up actual statistics on U.S. personal income, taxation, and government spending. A correct understanding of all three is required to determine things like Americans' tax-paying ability and tax fairness.
So let's look at the truth, starting on the personal income side.
Between 1947 and 1973, the typical American family's income roughly doubled in real terms. Not so after. Excluding the top percentile, from 1976 to 2007, average real incomes in the U.S. grew by only 17.9 percent, compared to, say, 26.4 percent income growth among the bottom 99 percent in France over the same period.
Meanwhile, the top 1 percent of U.S. income earners captured 58 percent of total income growth. And between 1979 and 2007, after-tax income for the wealthiest 1 percent of Americans rose by 281 percent!
Meanwhile, the top 1 percent of U.S. income earners captured 58 percent of total income growth. And between 1979 and 2007, after-tax income for the wealthiest 1 percent of Americans rose by 281 percent!
Correspondingly, real average U.S. wages have been flat since 1973, with a slight uptick from 1995-2001, but over the past two years actually falling, although U.S. workers' productivity (output per hour) has increased steadily over the entire period. (See income-output charts here.) Economics tells us that rising productivity translates to rising income; refer to the figures above to see where most of that income went.
Today the average per capita income of Americans is $25,000; and real median household income is below $50,000. 46,000,000 Americans must rely on food stamps. Two-thirds of Americans could not scrape together $1,000 for an emergency expense right now if they had to. And one-third of Americans has no savings.
By contrast, today the top 20 percent of income earners owns 75 percent of all U.S. net wealth, with the top 1 percent alone owning about 35 percent of all net wealth and 43 percent of all financial wealth. Furthermore, the top 10 percent controls 98 percent of all financial securities, and 81 percent of all stocks and mutual funds. The top 1 percent alone controls 61 percent of all financial securities! (To put this much financial wealth into historical context, consider that, even with its recent falls, the Dow Jones Industrial Average today is higher than it was in the bubble period of early 2006, as is today's NASDAQ, so the rich are still doing very well for themselves.)
Perhaps most tellingly, today the 400 wealthiest Americans own more wealth than the bottom 50 percent of all American households. You have to reach back to the Great Depression to find income inequality this great.
Next, the taxation side.
Faced with a national debt approaching $15 trillion, and a recent report that Americans are paying the smallest share of their income in taxes since 1958, it seems logical -- nay, unavoidable, to consider tax increases. But taxes on whose income? Again, let's briefly look at the history that got us here.
From 1965 to 1978, the top marginal tax rate was steady at 70 percent for individuals making at least $100,000, heads of households making at least $180,000, and married couples making over $200,000.
Then under Ronald Reagan, as income inequality inexplicably increased, the tax burden on Americans shifted from the very rich to everybody else: in 1982 he cut off the top three income brackets, thereby reducing the top rate to 50 percent, and set the top income threshold at $85,600 for couples, $41,500 for singles, and $60,600 for heads of households. Later Reagan further reduced the top rate to 38.5 percent, then 28 percent.
More significantly, over two terms Reagan reduced the number of tax brackets from 16 to five to only two. This last change, with the 1987 tax reform act, was nominally a tax decrease of $8.9 billion, but what it did was flatten the overall tax burden, making it less progressive, i.e. "shared sacrifice" in Prof. Carter's terms. (See Reagan's budget director Bruce Bartlett's instructive op-ed on the flattening of federal income tax rates from Reagan to the present.)
In 1992, G.H.W. Bush inched the top rate up to 31 percent by adding a third (top) bracket, caught hell for it from Republicans, and lost the next election to a mega-rich right-leaning third-party candidate. Then during the economic boom of the Clinton years, the top rate was increased slightly to 40 percent; meanwhile, Clinton added two top tax brackets for individuals making over $115,000 or heads of households making over $127,000, i.e. taxes on the middle class hardly increased. Clinton's nudge back toward the historical norm was labelled by Republicans as "the largest peacetime tax increase in American history." Incidentally, Clinton ended his second term with the first U.S. budget surplus since -- there's that fateful year again -- 1973.
And during the G.W. Bush years the top rate was lowered to 35 percent, where it remains today for single or head of household tax filers earning over $379,000 per year. Bush also added a new bottom rate of 10 percent.
Overall, we can see that, starting in the 1980s, the rich sloughed the tax burden off their shoulders and onto those of the middle class, whose income was never sufficient to cover rising federal expenditures.
Although it is true, as many Republicans remind us, that the richest 20 percent of Americans pays nearly 70 percent of federal taxes, and the top 1 percent alone pays nearly 30 percent, it is also true that the richest 20 percent earns more than 60 percent of all U.S. income, and the top 1 percent alone earns more than 20 percent. From that perspective, our tax system appears only mildly progressive.
If we look at all taxes (federal, state, and local) -- although Prof. Carter instructs us not to -- and compare them to relative incomes, then we clearly see how the system skews toward the very rich's favor. The top 20 percent (top quintile) of U.S. income earners pays about 30 percent of its annual income in taxes, whereas the bottom 20 percent (bottom quintile) pays about 17 percent of its income, the second quintile pays about 20 percent, the third (middle) quintile pays 25 percent of its income, and the fourth quintile pays nearly 29 percent. That is, overall effective U.S. tax rates are highly regressive. Which Prof. Carter says he is against.
As a final note on taxes, I must respond to Carter's misleading statement that, "When almost half of households pay no federal income taxes, the concept of shared sacrifice vanishes, and America becomes not that to which we contribute but that from which we receive." Indeed, about 46 percent of U.S. households will have no tax liability in 2011, but 17 percent of them because they are elderly with little or no income. Given their lifetime of working and paying taxes, we should be fine with that. So actually less than 30 percent of households pays no income tax, and of those, 28.3 percent does pay payroll tax (plus state and local taxes). Lastly, not to get too wonky but, due to popular tax credits, much of that 28.3 percent does pay federal income tax, too, they just get it refunded once a year, hence they do "share the pain" of having income tax deducted from every paycheck as they try to make ends meet, although I realize that doesn't lower the deficit.
That leads us, finally, to the federal spending side.
The income disbalances and flattening of tax rates described above started at about the same time the U.S. started to rack up massive annual budget deficits, first under Jimmy Carter (-$288 billion), then ballooning under Ronald Reagan by $1.8 trillion, G.H.W. Bush by $1.4 trillion, Bill Clinton by $1.4 trillion, then G.W. Bush by $6.1 trillion (!). Much to everyone's dismay, since Barack Obama took office the federal debt has increased by about $4 trillion -- but this was mostly due to plummeting tax receipts, both from G.W. Bush's tax cuts (which Obama kept in place) and the worst economy since the Great Depression. (Note: only Bill Clinton decreased America's debt-to-GDP ratio, meaning the national economy grew faster than the national debt.)
One might suppose that all this spending went to shore up the incomes of poorer Americans, yet a comparative analysis of social spending shows the U.S. spends about as much as Canada and Australia as a percent of GDP, which both have a much smaller debt-to-GDP ratio than the U.S. (Note: we should not include SS and Medicare in this discussion because they are not funded from income tax, the subject at hand). No, the biggest increase since the 1970s has been in defense spending, especially the $2 trillion already spent in Iraq and Afghanistan.
So we see that the same presidents who preached lower taxes on the rich were the same ones who blew up the national debt. Coincidence? I think not.
This is all related to the neo-liberal consensus over the past 30 years that: 1) the very rich, especially those who earn income from capital as opposed to wages, power our (consumption-driven) economy, while workers are but inputs who have no choice but to lower themselves to the cheapest standards of global labor supply; and 2) low taxation on the rich is the only economic instrument in government's toolbox, both in good times to reward them for their investments, and in bad times to encourage them to continue investing. The unspoken last word in this consensus is that 3) government spending is "out of control"... except for the things we can't live without. Too bad we can't agree what those are.
But back to Prof. Carter, who argues, basically, that it would not be fair to increase taxes on those Americans making more than $379,000 per year, nor would it be useful, because their income isn't great enough "to make a serious dent in the nation's debt."
Yet what is unfair about letting the Bush tax cuts expire for the top 2 percent, saving $700 billion over 10 years? Or better yet, going back to the 1986 top rate of 50 percent, and levying it on individuals making over $379,000 per year? And why not do as America's richest man Warren Buffet suggested, and create new top tax brackets for those making over $1 million (about 315,000 households or 375,000 individual taxpayers) and $10 million (over 8,000 households) per year? Indeed, if the super rich don't have any money to pay off our nation's debt, as Carter claims, then my goodness, who in America does?
Beyond a real progressive income tax, there are other ways to share our sacrifice, like a 0.5 percent financial transaction tax as in the UK and EU, which could raise over $175 billion per year in the U.S. yet hardly be felt by individual investors. And various luxury or excise taxes. Not to mention closing corporate tax loopholes and shutting down offshore tax havens, which, according to the NYT, have helped to reduce the corporate share of U.S. tax receipts from 30 percent in the 1950s to 6.6 percent in 2009.
Carter purports to show why Democrats and Republicans are both wrong on taxes, but he spends most of his op-ed urging cuts in federal employees' salaries and tax increases on the bottom half of income earners, both of which Democrats oppose. Well this Democrat smells a red herring. Morally, historically and arithmetically Carter's arguments don't add up.
Happy Labor Day!
By Stephen L. Carter
September 1, 2011 | Bloomberg
Taxes are in bad political odor these days. True, there has been no era in which taxation was popular, but we seem to have reached a moment of particular confusion. We have one major party dedicated to the bizarre principle that nothing that is not taxed now should ever be taxed again, and another dedicated to the equally bizarre principle that taxes are a magical elixir that will eliminate the nation's indebtedness while touching only those who happen to own private jets.
In this strange and wondrous atmosphere, I would like to say a word or two in defense of taxation, and then to suggest that each party is on the track of an important truth, even if, in the rush for partisan advantage, each also misunderstands the virtues of its own position.
Taxes will inevitably go up. The Democrats are right about that much. Alas, they get the reason wrong every time they try to explain. The reason taxes must rise is not that millionaires and billionaires have too much money, or that corporations aren't paying their fair share. It's that the federal government, under the joint leadership of the two parties, has fallen so deeply into debt that its need has grown desperate. Under no plausible scenario are we going to grow ourselves out of the remarkable hole we have dug. In what ought to be a national embarrassment, our government needs more revenue to pay not for a more glorious future but for a tragically wasted past.
Narrow Tax Base
The Republicans, too, are wrong, in their opposition to any increase in any taxes for any reason. But they are right that the Democrats have made an absurd fetish of progressivity, and that the constant chatter about asking the rich to sacrifice makes it sound as if taxes are the punishment one suffers for success. And they are right in admitting, in their unguarded moments, what the Simpson-Bowles Commission pointed out: that the tax base is too narrow.
[ Progressivity isn't a "fetish," it's both a moral fairness question -- those who earn more, pay more -- and a question of math -- the bottom income earners in America have nothing to contribute to federal coffers: they have zero or negative net worth, and will for the next decade at least, since the housing bubble was their only source of wealth. - J ]
The middle of a fragile recovery may not be the proper time to increase taxes. This is particularly true given that Americans are, at the moment, highly leveraged, and many might have to take on additional debt in order to pay additional taxes. Perhaps we would be wise to wait until what Harvard University economist Kenneth Rogoff calls "the Great Contraction" -- getting rid of debt -- has run its course.
But rise taxes eventually will, and, if we are smart, they will cover a broader base. Indeed, it is at once amusing and depressing to hear all the talk of shared sacrifice when we are discussing tax increases mainly on those earning more than $250,000 a year. Part of the magic of this figure may be that few federal employees get paid as much. But one in five earns upward of $100,000 a year.
This is worth mentioning because there isn't much in the way of shared sacrifice when a taxpayer who makes, say, $275,000 a year has to pay an extra 3 percent on the amount over $250,000 ($750) while a civil servant earning, say, $175,000 a year retains all of her income. Bear in mind that a tax increase is, in effect, a reduction in income. If sacrifice is to be truly shared, why not ask federal employees to accept an across-the- board salary reduction of, say, 2 percent?
Shared Sacrifice
True, this wouldn't yield much revenue. The most recent publicly available figures, for 2009, put federal nondefense salary spending at a bit more than $15 billion a month, or $180 billion a year. Even if (as seems likely) the figure has now reached $200 billion, a 2 percent cut would save a mere $4 billion annually. Yet, as a symbolic gesture, it would do far more than any presidential address to convince voters that the government is serious about shared sacrifice.
I don't suggest this plan because I think federal employees are overpaid. I don't. But neither are the vast majority of those who happen to earn more than $250,000 in the private sector. Still, if cutting federal salaries in return for cutting the income of other taxpayers seems too much to ask, perhaps we should consider another way of sharing the sacrifice: We should broaden the tax base. Simpson-Bowles suggests reducing rates as part of the broadening, while also removing most deductions. Many liberals object that the plan would reduce the progressivity of the tax code. But this response is a non sequitur.
The progressive tax structure rests upon the eminently sensible notion that those who earn more should be taxed at a higher rate. Those of us who have benefited more -- whether because of hard work or good luck or, probably most often, some combination of the two -- ought to pay a larger part of the revenue burden. We can afford it, and, as my late father often reminded me (borrowing without attribution from Oliver Wendell Holmes), to pay taxes to the government of the U.S. is a privilege.
But progressivity is merely one factor in working out tax rates. It isn't the reason taxes exist. They exist to raise revenue, a point easily forgotten in the rhetoric of the day. And there isn't nearly enough income in the upper bracket to make a serious dent in the nation's debt.
Liberals are fond of quoting from a 1936 speech in which President Franklin Roosevelt decried "a small but powerful group which has fought the extension of those benefits, because it did not want to pay a fair share of their cost." Nice line. But it's easy to forget that F.D.R., in the very same paragraph, reminded his listeners of the "vast majority of citizens who believe the benefits of democracy should be extended and who are willing to pay their fair share to extend them."
Paying More
Precisely right. A vast majority of Americans should be willing to pay taxes. All but the very poorest should contribute financially to the great American experiment. The shared sacrifice should certainly be progressive, but it should also be shared. When almost half of households pay no federal income taxes, the concept of shared sacrifice vanishes, and America becomes not that to which we contribute but that from which we receive.
(It is frequently said, in response to this argument, that almost all employed Americans are taxed by the federal government, because they pay Social Security and Medicare taxes. But these, at least in theory, are special-purpose levies, flowing into accounts that will someday benefit the payer personally. If in fact these fees simply constitute a part of the tax burden for general purposes of governance, Washington is free to confess at any time to decades of misleading the public.)
Taxes are in themselves neither good nor evil, and both parties should stop talking as though they are. They are simply one among many ways of raising revenue. There was a time when the federal government relied almost entirely on import duties for its income. Lately its addiction has been to borrowed money. Perhaps a future generation will discover some other magical means for supporting the state. In the meanwhile, if indeed we need to sacrifice, let's at least sacrifice together.
[ This is a lame attempt by Carter to set up an "equal wrong" on both sides so he can knock down Democrats. But Democrats have never blessed or glorified taxation as a virtue in itself. Certainly no politician is dumb enough to call taxes "good," but only necessary. On the other hand, Republicans do call taxation "stealing" and IRS agents "thieves" and "thugs." - J ]
No comments:
Post a Comment